Saturday 16 December 2017

Dynamic Personalised Pricing - what it means to the consumer



On a project recently at a retailer, we broached the idea of dynamic personalised pricing. The basic idea is to identify each customer via facial recognition, using all relevant activities of the customer both online and in bricks and mortar, determine a price for specific items that we would like to offer the customer. The operationalisation would involve informing the customer of this offer and range from app notification, sms/instant messaging...

It’s not that difficult to pull-off, but you need quite a bit of investment in hardware, and ideally some changes to the bricks and mortar layout. The idea, of course, is to increase sales and profits by selling stuff to customers at prices they are likely to accept. However it also means you pay more for your quinoa than I do, since I am most likely less health conscious than you are.
How does that make you feel, as a customer?

Let me first start by explaining how this is viewed in Economics.

Imagine you are on a hot beach, and a financially savvy genie offers you ice-cream. How much are you willing to pay for your first ice-cream? May be $3? How about your second? Well since you would be less hot and thirsty, may be $2.50 since you enjoy the second ice-cream less than the first. And $1.80 for the third since you are starting to get sick of ice-cream...



Let’s say you feel greedy and decide you’d like to buy 3 ice-creams. What price will you pay? In a normal world, you will pay a flat price, and that’s would be $1.80 for each ice-cream. You wouldn’t buy a 4th ice-cream at $1.80 because you’d be willing to pay only say $1.2 for it. The total you pay for the ice-cream is 3x$1.80=$5.40.




But this is a genie world, and the genie would prefer to sell you the first ice-cream at $3, the second at $2.50 and the thirst at $1.80.  Hence you would pay $7.30. The key is that the genie has used his/her powers to understand you r willingness to pay and exploited that. The genie can convince you to buy a 4th ice-cream by selling it to you at $1.20 (as long as the ice-cream costs less than $1.20 to produce the genie is still making higher profits).




Let’s just focus on the 3 ice-creams; in one case you pay $5.40, in the other $7.30. The difference, that is $1.90, is called the consumer surplus in economics. It’s a monetary value of the difference between how much you are willing to pay and how much you do pay. In the normal case you, as consumer, enjoy the consumer surplus, in the genie world he captures the consumer surplus and it becomes ‘genie surplus’.

Things become more interesting if your calorie conscious friend is next to you on the beach. He is only willing to pay $2.40 for the first ice-cream he consumes and $1.80 for the second, $1.00 for the third.



In a normal world, at price of $1.80, you would get 3 ice-creams with a surplus of $1.90 to you, and your friend gets 2 ice-creams with a surplus of $0.60 (he pays $3.60 but would have been willing to pay $4.20). The total surplus consumes enjoy is $2.50 ($1.90 to you, $0.60 to your friend).

The greedy genie eats up your entire surplus and that of your friend by personalising the prices, each one of you pays a different price for each ice-cream.

In Economics, this is called “price discrimination”, setting different prices for the same product to different people/markets. The word “discrimination” has certain connotations and was chosen accordingly.

Why should the genie stop there? He/she is after all a greedy one.

There is no simply no reason for the genie to charge both you and your friend $1.80. For example, he might decide that the heat is a good reason to try and make your friend more appreciative of the joys of ice-cream and sell a third ice-cream to your friend at $1.00. The genie has a plan to nudge your friend away from the calorie counting days to the more indulgent path. For you, the genie decides that you will still buy ice-cream tomorrow anyway, so he shouldn’t decrease the price so much.


Now, you and your friend are paying very different prices. What do you feel? Does it matter? Is the price you are willing to pay for something independent of how much your friend pays?

How about the dynamic piece would you ask?

Now let’s say the temperature goes up. A hot wind has started to blow.

The benefits you derive from the ice-creams increase. It is hotter; you and your friend are now willing to pay 20 cents more for every ice cream.


In ‘old school’ where prices are printed, there’s nothing much the seller can do. So you enjoy $0.60 more of surplus and your friend enjoys $0.40 extra. 

A programmatic system could tie the price of ice-cream to temperature, and the price of ice-cream goes up by $0.20, and the seller captures this increase in your (and your friend’s) willingness to pay by taking advantage of dynamic pricing (think of the supermarkets where prices are electronically set and can be easily changed). There is no personalisation yet.


Every unit is sold at the same price; it’s just that the increase in willingness to pay across the board has allowed the seller to charge 20cents more for every unit. Only the surplus on the last units is completely captured by the seller, the rest deliver the same amount of surplus as previously (because we assumed an increase of $0.2 across the board and the price rose by $0.2 too).


In the world of price discrimination, the supplier can also easily absorb the increase in willingness to pay. How about personalised dynamic pricing?



You can bet the genie will instantly scoop up this extra $1.20 of surplus by selling you the ice-creams at $3.20, $2.70, and $2.00 and your friend at $2.60, $2.00 and $1.20 since he still wants to convert your friend).

The question is how far are we from the genie’s world?

We are already there; as I mentioned at the start, this was part of a discussion with a prospect. (no worries, they didn’t bite. Yet.)

The article by the guardian (1) that inspired this article mentions it is easier to implement dynamic personalised pricing online; that is true, but it is actually not that difficult in the bricks and mortar world too; all that is required is to invest in cameras (security camera feeds can be used). The physical equivalent of hovering your mouse over a product is you spending time looking at that product on the shelves isn’t it? The only thing that needs to be determined is whether the hover is because of the product or because of some distraction (and it is easier from a camera feed).

Where the organisation really can exploit the customer is when you combine online and bricks and mortar behaviour (via customer identification and proper data integration/customer 360/scv...), the organisation can even drive customers to different channels, all this then ends up in the domain of personalised customer journeys.

Most organisations are not at this stage of analytical maturity yet.

So what can you do as a consumer if you do not agree to be exploited/discriminated?

One way out is arbitraging: get your calories counting friend to buy the ice-cream and sell it to you, you’ll both be better off. Another way is to play different providers against each other; find a different genie and compare prices – at this moment price comparison may be expensive, but more and more price aggregators are popping up, making the cost of comparing lower. Store products and take advantage of lower prices...

Hopefully there will still be alternatives to dynamic personalised pricing, going “old school” isn’t a bad idea; in fact one of the competitors to Uber for example is advertising the fact that its prices are predetermined.

(1) https://www.theguardian.com/global/2017/nov/20/dynamic-personalised-pricing